121022_iit_cluster_game_pq.indd
A Novel, Game Theory-Based Approach to Better Understand Incentives and Stability in Clusters
Endre Gedai, László Á. Kóczy, Zita Zombori
László Á. Kóczy
Gerd Meier zu Köcker,
Institute for Innovation and Technology, iit (Berlin)
Thomas A. Christensen
Danish Ministry for Science, Technology and Innovation,
DASTI (Copenhagen)
Copenhagen, Berlin 2012
Countries all over the world look for ways to increase their competitiveness. The contribution of cooperating com-
panies in the form of clusters is rather substantial and therefore, for example, the European Union and its member
states have long been supporting these cooperative efforts. This support may take the form of a more entrepre-
neur-friendly legal environment, initiate cooperation, but it may also mean non-returnable financial contribution.
This paper does not want to discuss the optimal channels to support clusters, and in particular it does not want to
study the ways financial contributions are distributed among clusters. Rather, the contribution is an entirely novel
way to look at the forces that keep some clusters on track while destruct others.
Longstanding cooperation between companies forms a special complex process hierarchy in clusters. The main
businesses of the cluster is driven by the actors' interests in staying competitive, improving competitiveness and
obtaining high profits both as a cluster, but especially as an individual company. Cooperation and the actors'
selfish interests should be kept in balance or else the success of the cluster is in jeopardy and its actors can
lose both joint and individual profits. Organic relationships and cooperation among companies or a favourable
business environment is, by no means a guarantee for a working and successful cluster. Clusters operating at
industrial concentration points, having a critical mass, supporting environment, and a successful cluster manager
may nevertheless lack success. On the other hand other clusters operating in suboptimal circumstances in theory,
flourish and produce a high extra profit in practice. This puzzle cries for new models, new approaches for a better
understanding of the opportunities and decisions that drive the clusters and their actors.
This paper introduces an entirely novel way to study clusters by looking at the selfish, profit-seeking interests
of the entrepreneurs, the actors of clusters. The approach, using game theory provides an exact, mathematical
framework to study the conflict between the fruitful cooperation represented by the cluster and the selfish ways
of the actors to follow their own – possibly short term – interests. The game theoretic approach makes it possible
to identify not only good or bad clusters, provide recipes for solutions in some of the bad clusters, but also to
define golden rules that do not only facilitate the evaluation of existing clusters, but help future cluster managers
to create better, more stable clusters.
Table of contents
Executive summary . 3
Clusters and game theory . 7
I.1 Cooperation of the companies . 7
I.4 Cluster policies and cluster-based economic development . 9
I.5 The cluster management organisation . 10
I.6 Key elements – Trust and social capital . 10
theory . 13
II.1 Non-cooperative
II.2 Cooperative
III Cluster
games . 21
III.1 Where are the coalitions in clusters? . 21
III.2 About translating clusters into games . 23
III.3 The bases of decision making: Do actors like profit? . 24
III.4 Cluster code – structure: Do actors think about present and future alternatives? . 26
IV Setting the golden rules . 27
IV.1 Joining a cluster: Do actors look for profit? . 27
IV.2 Cluster code: How to keep all cluster actors happy at the same time? . 29
IV.3. Social networks: How do projects form? . 30
V Hypothesis
testing. 31
V.1 Fundamentals of decision making . 31
V.2 Profitability
V.3 Networks . 32
V.4 Conclusions on the data . 32
VI Conclusion . 33
VII Bibliography . 34
VIII Authors . 37
Zita Zombori . 37
László Á. Kóczy . 37
Clusters and game theory
Clusters and game theory
Today the formation of clusters – the collaboration of compa-
Without being absorbed in a form and content analysis of the
nies with each other and with the research sector – is seen as a
companies and the institutions in contact with them, it is nec-
possibility to renew the economy and the society. Clusters have
essary to mention the classification made by Jacobs and De
been proven as a very promising tool to strengthen the com-
Man. They define clusters in a three-fold manner as either be-
petitiveness of companies all over the world. Competitiveness
ing regionally located, as possessing a vertical production and
significantly increases among cluster actors which are closely
supply chain process or third, as businesses that are related by
located within a region and willing to do joint research, devel-
some form of narrowly-focused specialization. Links the cluster
opment as well as to jointly create innovations. Clusters offer
definitions to the development of industrial policy in The Neth-
a favourable and dynamic business environment (ecosystem)
erlands, and from the discussion compiles a menu of possible
where innovative companies can flourish by interacting with
policies and strategies that can be utilized by both industry and
different innovation actors and across sectoral boundaries.
government for the furtherance of industrial policy. (Jacobs &
Recognizing these positive roles the development of clusters is
actively supported by policy makers worldwide.
In conclusion our opinion is that longstanding coopera-
tion between companies forms a special process making
Cooperation of the companies
complex hierarchy which main business motives basi-
cally are driven by the ideas of staying alive and being
History proves that humanity is ready for cooperation and it
competitive and strengthening this competitiveness as
needs cooperation. To put it simply, the modern enterprise is a
well as maximizing the profit.
typical product of modern people's cooperation and the rela-
tions between the enterprises and other organizations mean a
The fact that the forms of companies' cooperation are
more advanced stage in the cooperation's hierarchy.
continuously developing and this cooperation has a spe-
cial evolution progress – the successful solutions will be
Alfred Marshall in his book – Principles of Economics (Marshall,
commonly used and the less successful initiatives will
1890) – shed light on the positive effect of the concentration of
die – is noteworthy as well.
specialized industries in a particular area.
His concept was based on a pattern of organization that was
I.2 Clusters
common in late nineteenth century Britain in which compa-
nies concentrating on the manufacture of certain products
Moving on to the particular subject of the concept paper, it
were geographically clustered. Comments made by Marshall
would be worth beginning with a definition which clarifies
(1890, Book 4, Chapter 10) have been used by economists and
the concept of cluster, with one, which is fully accepted by the
economic geographers to discuss this phenomenon. The two
community. In the literature many alternative, overlapping defi-
dominant characteristics of a Marshallian industrial district are
nitions are used, but there is no commonly accepted standard.
high degrees of vertical and horizontal specialisation and a very
heavy reliance on market mechanism for exchange. Compa-
Actually, the most known definition of cluster had become
nies tend to be small and to focus on a single function in the
public as a result of Michael E. Porter's work. In the 80's Porter
production chain. Companies located in industrial districts are
studied the factors of competitiveness. In connection with this
highly competitive in the neoclassical sense, and in many cases
research he clarified the positive effect on the competitiveness
there is little product differentiation. The major advantages of
of the regional and sectoral cooperation.
Marshallian industrial districts arise from simple propinquity of
companies, which allows easier recruitment of skilled labour
The four factors of Porter's diamond model (company strategy,
and rapid exchanges of commercial and technical information
structure and rivalry; factor conditions; demand conditions; re-
through informal channels. They illustrate competitive capital-
lated and supporting industries) interact with each other to cre-
ism at its most efficient, with transaction costs reduced to a
ate conditions where innovation and improved competitiveness
practical minimum; but they are feasible only when economic
occur (Porter, 1990).
of scale are limited. (Wikipedia contributors, 2012; Zaratiegui,
Based on this theory he introduced the concept of clusters: ‘A
cluster is a geographically proximate group of interconnected
companies and associated institutions in a particular field linked
to realize higher profit than the total profit of the cluster
by commonalities and complementarities'. (Porter, 1998)
actors. From the point of view of this concept paper it
is important to emphasize the observation implemented
Ketels (2004) draws four critical characteristics to our atten-
in cluster definitions – cooperation and competition …
tion which is proximity, linkages, interactions and critical mass.
both of them are characteristic for the cluster actors at
Understanding the importance of these four dimensions is
the same time. But these two opposite attitudes should
much more important than defining specific benchmarks along
be kept in balance among the cluster actors under any
them that a group of companies and institutions have to meet
circumstances, otherwise either overweight could
to be called a cluster.
jeopar dize the success of the cluster.
‘The geographic scope of clusters can vary from a single city,
state or region to a network of companies across state or even
I.3 Cluster
country borders. There are various clustering forms that may
ensue to optimise competitive advantage. Clustering can be
Thanks to the work of Porter the positive impact of the clus-
formal or informal, in the public or private sector; horizontal
ters on the regional economy has become well known fast for
or vertical; physical; and even sometimes virtual. In horizon-
policy makers responsible for economic development. Taking
tal clustering companies within the same industry sector are
the advantage of this theory numerous economic strategies
co-located in a particular geographic area and might share an
have tried to get the benefit of the clusters' operation. The
industrial or technological base, operate within a common mar-
successful clusters can integrate the regional capacities with
ket and use a common purchasing and/or distribution channel
the special knowledge in their own value chain, which result
(Michael, 2003). Vertical networks include horizontal cluster
is an advantage that is hardly reached by others. The cluster
participants as well as supply chain members such as suppli-
itself is a favourable business environment for the SME's and
ers, consumers and related services (Boekholt, 1997). Diago-
it helps them (directly and indirectly as well), to easy connect
nal clustering refers to the concentration of complementary or
to the international economic trends. We can say that the clus-
symbiotic activities, whereby each company adds value to the
ters can be ready to be the heart not only of the well-working
other.' (Braun, McRae-Williams, & Lowe, 2005)
companies but of the regional development as well, thus if the
cooperation-culture becomes general and is widely used in a
The changes and the improvements of the cluster definition
region, the development of a favourable business environment
were induced by the realization of the influence of the organi-
is only a child's play.
zations and institutions working in interaction in the market on
the competitiveness and by the realization of the various forms
Cluster development programmes based on economic politi-
of cooperation of the cluster's framework.
cal decisions proved that without (strong) base or a suitable
approach there is no success, there are no successful initiatives.
‘Comparing the diversity of cluster definitions and approaches
Examples for such failures are PANAC (Hungary) or IT Öresund
throughout the literature, three common elements emerge:
(Sweden and Denmark).
geographic, economic integration, and social elements. In the
literature, these elements are further divided into a number
Nowadays it is a fact that the cluster itself can be a useful
of dimensions (Bryant & Wells, 1998; Enright, 2000; Harrison,
instrument in the economic development, but if the cluster
1992; Jacobs & De Man, 1996; Rosenfeld, 1997, 2001; Verbeek,
funding itself has become the central goal for the cluster actors
1999), such as geographic localisation, vertical and horizontal
and/or for the economic leaders, then the cluster can miss lose
aggregation, innovation, critical mass, and social networks.'
his basis basically needed to success. Clusters have to be con-
(McRae-Williams, 2004)
sidered as tools not as an objective.
We consider it important to mention that the essence
Regarding the cluster development our starting-point is
of clusters is based on empirical examinations and on a
that the clusters are ‘the product' of a long term evolu-
bottom up procedure. Funding and/or organizing a clus-
tionary process and at the same time they are a success-
ter is an organic instrument of the member companies to
ful instrument of the companies' struggle for survival
increase their competitiveness, which has a (back) posi-
and of obtaining (high) profit. One must therefore pay
tive effect on geographical and economic circumstances
attention to the cluster fundamentals, and the cluster's
of a cluster as well. Moreover cluster is an economic
motivations when evaluating a cluster's plan of opera-
device in the competitiveness development, with which
effective utilisation of a region's resources it is possible
Clusters and game theory
Cluster policies and cluster-
teristics of these programs. Let us summarize the most impor-
based economic development
Studies about the companies' cooperation have outlined the
‘Common to all programs is their rationale of increas-
role of geographical concentration of different activities and
ing the competitiveness of the national economy through
the conurbational benefits coming from it. From the point of
the facilitation of collaboration between companies and
view of the development of the cluster it is essential that poten-
research stakeholders.' (Lämmer-Gamp, Meier zu Köcker,
tial actors are present in ample number in geographical area,
& Christensen, 2011, p 34) But there are different types of
exceeding the critical mass. Therefore if statistical evidence
the 16 cluster programs which serve different purposes.
suggests that in a given geographical area the companies,
The analysis of the objectives and strategies of the different
which are willing to join a cluster, are present in higher than
cluster program reveals the following main types of cluster
the average density and their number, size and economic im-
portance achieve the critical mass, an industrial cluster organi-
I) Cluster programs that focus on regional economic develop-
sation can be founded or the formation is already in progress.
This method was adopted by Ketels & Sölvell (2004) in order to
II) Cluster programs that focus on the development of national
map the new member states' cluster organisations.
III) Cluster programs that focus on the commercial exploitation
In the recent years the European Union and some member
of the R&D potential of a country's economy
states have rightly committed considerable effort and resource
‘Network programs to support the competitiveness of
to the deeper understanding of clusters. Looking at the Euro-
national industries.' (Lämmer-Gamp, Meier zu Köcker, &
pean cluster landscape it becomes clear that some clusters are
Christensen, 2011, pp 44–45) ‘Most programs support both
more successful than others. Which clusters will likely be suc-
the establishment of new cluster management organizations
cessful? Which of these is it worth investing in?
and the future development of already existing matured
cluster management organizations. Only a few programs
‘In order to facilitate the discussion about cluster policy through
concentrate either on the establishment of new cluster
further insights into the characteristics of clusters and cluster
organizations or the further development of already exist-
policy intervention, the Danish Ministry of Research, Innova-
ing matured cluster organizations.' (Lämmer-Gamp, Meier
tion and Higher Education, supported by the German Federal
zu Köcker, & Christensen, 2011, p 35) e. g. Competence Net-
Ministry of Economics and Technology and its national cluster
work Germany, Cluster Offensive Bayern, Norwegian Cen-
program Initiative Kompetenznetze Deutschland, the Nordic
tres of Expertise, Arena and Strategic Research Program for
Council of Ministers and the Nordic Innovation Centre (NICe),
Centres of Excellence and Research Clusters.
have initiated the project 'NGPExcellence – Cluster Excellence in
‘Most programs do not have particular strategic objectives
the Nordic Countries, Germany and Poland'. The overall objec-
in terms of actors of clusters that are funded, restrictions on
tive of this project is to contribute to the development of out-
thematic areas and coverage of the most important business
standing clusters through excellent management and excellent
sectors.' (Lämmer-Gamp, Meier zu Köcker, & Christensen,
cluster programs. … This project pays particular attention on
2011, p 37) Only Innovation Networks Denmark, the Nor-
characteristics of cluster management organizations and their
wegian Centres of Expertise Program and the Cluster Policy
effects on cluster development. … As many cluster manage-
Strategy of the Free and Hanseatic City of Hamburg concen-
ment organizations are supported through national funding
trate their efforts on the most important business sectors of
programs the project also analyzed 16 cluster programs from
the economy.
nine countries in a benchmarking exercise to facilitate a bet-
‘Grant funding is the main instrument of nearly all cluster
ter understanding of successful strategies and mutual learn-
programs, while technical assistance for capacity develop-
ing between the program owners. The project, … , addressed
ment of cluster management organizations and its members
two target groups: On the one hand, managers and staff of
is applied by only half of the programs.' (Lämmer-Gamp,
the cluster and network organizations from the participating
Meier zu Köcker, & Christensen, 2011, p 39) ‘The most pro-
countries, and on the other hand, program owners and policy
grams co-fund initiatives to 50 or 75 per cent of the total
makers responsible for national cluster and network programs
project budget' (Lämmer-Gamp, Meier zu Köcker, & Chris-
and policies.' (Lämmer-Gamp, Meier zu Köcker, & Christensen,
tensen, 2011, p 41) and a number of cases there is no maxi-
2011, pp 10–11)
mum funding period for a project or maximum amount of
funding an applicant can apply for.
The examination of 16 different cluster programs in Europe
gave the authors a unique opportunity to describe the charac-
Looking at the European cluster policy landscape it becomes
policies to newly emerging needs and challenges and exchange
obvious that there are similarities but there is no common 'rec-
knowledge and experience on the evaluation and impact
ipe' for cluster policies, moreover there is no common 'recipe'
assessment of cluster programmes.' (European Cluster Confer-
for the success, just there are recommendations. The most im-
ence, 2012, p 3).
portant ones were given by the European Cluster Policy Group
issued in 2011. Building on them the INNO-Net project, the
This concept paper does not deal directly with the ques-
TACTICS Reflection Group – the objective of which is to as-
tion of the clusters' support, but it is even important
sist the TACTICS' partners to analyse, develop and propose
from some point of view. We have to note though that
new cluster policy actions and methods of implementation in
the subsidies of the clusters do deform or could deform
a number of predefined topics such as channelling RDI fund-
the organic (economic) process of a cluster development.
ing through excellent clusters or user-driven excellent clusters,
It can happen that the prime motivation of the cluster
among others – will issue in 2012 two handbooks on Cluster
will be the extra profit getting with the help of subsi-
internationalisation and Cluster marketing & branding.
dies or simply the subsidies will become a real part of
the profit. Therefore the cluster actors will get a false
Is it worth supporting clusters and if yes, how? – such ques-
understanding of the cluster's operation and about its
tions raise a heated debate. As we mentioned before, different
outcome. In any case – we should take these facts into
solutions are adopted. Which one of these is the best? Should
account at the evaluation of a cluster's operation.
we give alternative possibilities for the subsidies for the cluster
managers or for the cluster organizations or for the common
cluster actors' projects or just for developing a favourable busi-
The cluster management
ness environment? The success of the cluster development poli-
cies can be measured only after years. And the next question
this entails: How is it appropriate to measure the effects and
The cluster management is the result of the conscious clus-
impacts of clusters? The evaluation targets could be the target
ter development whose task is among others to stimulate the
policy or the cluster program or the cluster organization itself
organic development of the cooperation within the cluster
or the cluster management. The kind of the evaluation could be
with the help of accelerating the information flow and the
ex-post, ex-ante, formative, impact evaluation or benchmark-
project generation and providing the necessary competences.
ing or quality labelling. (Meier zu Köcker & Kind, 2012). More
Of course, the right cluster manager cannot even substitute
analyses were born even in the last few months (e. g. Joenneum
the cooperation between the cluster actors and cannot replace
Research – Policies Graz or The SLIM Project in Sweden). It can
the essential motives of the cluster's operation but it can really
be seen that Europe and the member states are different and
catalyze the cluster development not only with the realization
not unified. Taking the national characteristics, the ways and
of the above mentioned task but with right position of the mar-
the methods of the national developments into consideration,
keting & branding and internationalization strategy and with
companies with different conditions and structures, and then
solving the problems, debates, etc. The services offered by the
cooperative and competitive economics have developed
cluster manager shall be colourful based on the demand and
there are regions where it is worth to strengthen the ideas of
habit of the cluster actors and on the activity of the cluster. The
cluster initiatives with any kind of support and thereby stimulat-
most important thing is that the cluster manager shall not want
ing the development of the cooperation's culture and speeding
to get the upper hand over the cluster. Moreover the cluster
up the infrastructure development of cluster organisations and
manager cannot lose sight of the fact that the cluster's success
generating the joint investment projects of the cluster actors.
always depends on the actors and on their original aim – to
Parallel to it we have to say that there are regions where the
achieve the maximum profit via cooperation.
direct subsidies for the cluster organisations are not necessary
at all because the main aim and motivation of the cluster actors
are the realizable certain and high profit through their coopera-
Key elements – Trust and social
As it was written in the Vienna Cluster Manifesto as well ‘The
It must be mentioned that a 'program' cannot be successful
Commission shall further support the statistical analyses of
if the interested parties do not trust each other, they do not
clusters as provided in the framework of the European Clus-
co-operate or they are not committed to a long term, consist-
ter Observatory. … Member states and regions should, with
ent strategy. ‘The ability of people to work together for com-
support from the Commission, continue their policy dialogue
mon purposes in groups and organizations is the social capital
on cluster policy matters to further develop and adapt cluster
which is a capability that arises from the prevalence of trust in a
Clusters and game theory
society or in certain parts of it' (Fukuyama, 1995). ‘Further
1/ building up a cartel
developed the social capital is the existence of a certain set of
informal values or norms shared among members of a group
There are forms of the cooperation which are successful for the
that permit cooperation among them' (Fukuyama, 1999). It
actors but at the same time damaging for the economy (e. g.
‘refers to the collective value of all social networks and the
reducing the competition, agreement to the fix prices, market-
inclinations that arise from these networks to do things for
ing or production etc.). Cartels are illegal, but even so from
each other' (Putnam, 2000) ‘The literature has discussed
time to time the companies try to enter into such agreements.
social capital as a resource at the individual, organization, and
Cooperation and competition are characteristic for the relations
community level' (Strauss, 2010). ‘Social capital appears to be
of the cluster actors, too, but a successful cluster is not about
positively related to organizational effectiveness and to play a
the restriction of competition. We cannot, of course completely
central role in reducing organizational transaction costs' (Fuku-
exclude the possibility of parasites, undesirable groups of com-
yama, 1995). ‘It also facilitates coordinated action to achieve
panies that abuse cooperation and especially the support for
desired goals (Leana & Buren, 1999) justifies organizational
forming cooperation to reach their sinister goals.
commitment (Watson & Papamarcos, 2002), and results in a
significant positive impact on product innovation' (Nahapiet &
2/ no panacea
Ghoshal, 1998). But there are differences between the level of
the trust and the social capital of the countries, and these dif-
The well documented success-stories about the profitable and
ferences could appear among the regions of a country as well.
favourable effects of the cooperation in the frames of a cluster
might give the impression that joining a cluster will solve all
From the point of view of this concept paper the trust
business problems. Participation in a cluster might be a more
and the social capital is significant with a view to the
effective way to reach one's goals, but it should not be the goal
future profit of the trust and social capital. The return
itself. Managers, who wait for such a miracle, completely miss
in the cooperation invested resources is always awaited
the point and will fail miserably. Companies focussing on par-
just in the future.
ticipation only will not be able to benefit beyond the obtained
The present value of the awaited profit is being
decreased not only by the time-factors but by the risk
3/ herd attitude
of the distrust (e. g. changing of the economic regula-
tion, deficiency of the cooperation-rules, the problems
To found a cluster – it is trendy nowadays. Business actors often
of exercising a right). The more risk is recognised by the
feel that it is more profitable to join a cluster than to let the
cooperating partners the less but immediately provided
opportunity slip away. They do not really think of what this
advantage (profit) make them give up the cooperation.
seriously means in practice, they are just toying with the vision
of the word ‘cluster'. The idea of cluster is slowly becoming a
I.7 "Cluster
illnesses"
4/ lack of business and ambitions of the
In the last decades extensive studies have been conducted to
investigate and determine success-factors in clusters. During
the examinations the characteristics of the clusters have been
The cluster itself is an answer for the challenges of the eco-
analyzed from a number of points of view. On the basis of
nomic competition. Increasing the competitiveness of the com-
these examinations we can theoretically and statistically specify
panies the cluster gives them confidence that they will have
the kinds of clusters to be funded. Such conditions can specify
success in the fields of market struggle. The cluster is not a
the optimal number of cluster actors or the ideal competences
charity organisation, this is actually a secondary result of the
of the cluster managers . Theoretically it is also possible for
companies' activity. Misjudging where the cluster can help its
each of us to found and build a successful operating cluster or
actors can lead to bad experiences with any cooperation.
catalyze the process.
5/ isolation effect
Although the theoretical models have been proved in
the practical life many times, the practical experience is
If the cluster actors do not have enough information to make
not unanimous. What are the problems noticed during
the right decision on their own market position or market
the last years and the policy makers are willing to hush
share, then their cooperation is suffering from an isolation
effect and their results must be non-competitive in the global
market. It means if there is a product in the global market,
In the cases the cooperation between companies is
which is more easily and more cheaply available and moreover
not the result of an organic development. In a market
it has a better quality than the product of the cooperation, then
economy a company and its partners naturally have eco-
the cooperation itself is not successful. Why? Because with
nomic cooperation and if these relationships become
right assessment of the economic situation and also with hav-
serious and intensive then, the partners are ready to
ing marketable information and even with involving outsiders
pave the way for a cluster initiative. But … the natural
in the business, successful economic cooperation – including
relationships and cooperation between the companies,
the competitive products – would be easily guaranteed.
the industrial condensation points which helps the deve-
lopment of clusters and the favourable business environ-
6/ growing apace with the subsidies and
ment could not guarantee the development of a success-
grant dependency/rent seeking
ful and a self-supporting working cluster in an examined
area. On the one hand there are clusters recognised,
Getting subsidies for cluster development – this is the main
which operate at industry concentration points, have
business of the cluster, therefore the profit increase comes only
a suitable company size, supporting environment, a
from the subsidies.
successful cluster manager etc. and are not successful
despite these facts. On the other hand other clusters which
do not operate under above mentioned circumstances
and thus should in theory die, in practice flourish. These
The spread of this behaviour, getting the benefits of the opera-
facts suggest us to look deeper into the incentives in the
tion of a cluster without any willingness for real cooperation
operation of a cluster. After all, what drives the cluster
could jeopardize the success.
and its actors?
8/ extremes
The overconditioning and overregulation of the cluster's opera-
tion, the elaboration of complicated rules of procedure, the
forced and unnatural increase of the cluster actors' number put
high risk even on the operation of a successful cluster.
Game theory studies strategic conflict situations. What are the
crab sandwich they realise that they have some common inter-
characteristics of these situations? Firstly, the parties are
selfish:
ests: B could help company A to materialise this brilliant idea.
for a conflict of companies this simply means that they want
For reasons that we do not need to go into here B's help is
to maximise profits although in general the utility of the con-
not enough, at least two companies of this type are needed.
flict's outcome can manifest in various non-monetary forms,
Fortunately B has contacts with C and D, either of which can
too. Secondly, the conflict's outcome depends on the parties'
serve as a second company, in fact A, C and D could also realise
actions. We call the conflict situation a game and the involved
the project. The CEO of A finds the plan good and suggests
parties the players. The name probably comes from the fact
to share the expected extra profit of 12 million to be shared
that the father of game theory, the Hungarian genius John von
equally among the four actors of this cluster. Will this work?
Neumann was originally interested in developing a mathemati-
cal theory of bluffing in poker and his mathematical results
The shortest answer is: No. If the companies A, B and C can
found applications in economics and beyond only years, dec-
also do the project and obtain the same profit it would be fool-
ades later (von Neumann & Morgenstern, 1944).
ish to include D in the project and pay it 3 million, wouldn't
it? OK, D can stay on board, but with a much more modest
The
strategy of a player determines his actions for every possi-
share of the proceeds. Oh, but the same argument applies to
ble game scenario. As a result, given the strategies of the play-
B, or C that are of the same "type" of company as D. So, as a
ers, a game can be played and the outcome can be determined
matter of fact A takes all and the substitutable members of
by a mediator or a computer. Therefore the payoffs, such as
the group get almost nothing. Moreover, even over the little
profits of the players can also be determined once the strate-
payment they would get, the would start an eternal battle any
two of these trying to skim the third company by kicking it out
if the business.
We can describe a game in various forms, but there is one dif-
ference that divides games into two groups: cooperative and
We have only leaped over a tiny detail. A has no contact with
non-cooperative games. The difference is in the legal environ-
C or D. A can only cooperate with these companies if B helps
ment: noncooperative games are played in anarchy, in an en-
it, if B is on board, if you like: with B's permission. While com-
vironment where agreements are only kept if the parties are
panies A, C and D could realise the project, such a cooperation
interested in keeping them. In cooperative games, on the other
is simply not possible. But then B has a new, special role: B can
hand we assume that it is possible to make binding agree-
connect A with the right people. If we look at it again, there
ments. This distinction is largely due to Nash, who made key
are only two ways the project could be realised: A, B and C or
contributions to both types of games (Nash, 1950, 1953). While
A, B and D. As C and D can substitute each other, they will not
the language of the two types of games is remarkably differ-
get much of the (extra) profit, the profit is shared between A
ent researchers have shown that the conclusions drawn from
and B. They can share the profit equally as 6–6 millions, but if
the two types of models are essentially the same. The different
any other distribution emerges neither of them will have the
formulation, however means that the two types of games are
possibility to increase its share. After the offer of company A, B
used for different situations: noncooperative games are best
getting 9 millions is a likely outcome, for instance.
suited to study the detailed interaction of a few players, while
cooperative game theory can handle the interaction of large
We have noted that C and D are perfect substitutes, in other
groups of players. Since a cluster is a selfish cooperation of
words one of them is superfluous. So why did B suggest two
economic agents, cooperative game theory is the better suited
partners at the first place? Consider the same setting when D
of the two to study the interaction. Nevertheless we start with
is not there: Then only full cooperation of all the parties can
a few simple concepts from noncooperative game theory that,
realise the project. In such a setting B's role as intermediary is
on the one hand illustrate the modelling power of game theory
secondary, company C can rightly demand a share of the profit
better, and motivate our use of cooperative game theory later.
and this share is a loss to A and B. In other words A and B profit
But before we move on to the theory let us consider a simple
from having both C and D in the cluster.
Finally note that the assumption that a company will cooperate
Company A has a brilliant idea that could be developed into a
for zero profit might sound unrealistic. Of course this is zero
very successful and profitable idea – with the right partners.
economic, rather than accounting profit where the company
The CEO of A meets the CEO of B at a reception and over a
has been compensated for all production costs as well as its
opportunity cost (the cost of doing this project rather than in-
Suspect 1 Suspect 2
vesting its resources elsewhere) and a compensation for risk.
Getting a zero profit is therefore not the same as not getting
paid, but a higher profit is naturally preferred. In practice a zero
1 Prisoners' dilemma
profit case will not arise due to imperfect substitutes, capacity
constraints or switching costs, but these only mildly affect our
By the
solution of such a game we mean finding the strategies
the suspects (or players, in general) will choose. The difficulty
in finding the solution lies in the fact that the outcome and the
As we have said this story is simple, but real clusters have simi-
payoffs depend on the strategy of both players. In other words
lar, though naturally more complex interactions, where the
a player must choose his strategy making some assumption
same arguments could be used. In the more complex cases,
about the other player.
however the calculations may be a little more involved requir-
ing a more general and more formal treatment.
The inspection of the game in Table 1. suggests that the players
should choose (Deny, Deny) to get the highest utility. Unfor-
tunately these are criminals, so they might ignore a possible
II.1 Non-cooperative
agreement before the questioning they might act differently.
Indeed, if any of the suspects chooses the strategy Deny, the
A non-cooperative game consists of three elements. Firstly, N
other profits from Cooperate. Since the argument applies to
is the set of players {1,…,
n}, with a generic element denoted by
both criminals, it is not very realistic to assume that any of them
i.The set of strategies available to player
I is denoted by ∑. and
will think (Deny, Deny) is realistic. If one criminal chooses Co-
we denote a particular strategy by σ .1 A strategy profile σ is the
operate, the other's best response is Cooperate, too. This also
collection of all the individual strategies. ∑ collects all possible
means that if they agreed to (Cooperate, Cooperate) neither of
strategy profiles. The utility of a player determines the payoff
them would have a reason to act differently. This is precisely
of the player given the entire strategy profile. So, for instance,
the equilibrium we are looking for.
if the players have chosen the strategies σ, the payoff of player
i is given as u (σ).
We call a strategy profile σ* a
Nash-equilibrium of a game, if
the strategy chosen by any of the players is a best response to
First we explain the so-called Prisoners' dilemma. The story
the strategy of the others. Mathematically:
goes as follows: after a bank robbery two suspicious persons
are captured with illegal weapons. The police has no evidence
ui(σ*)≥ui(σi,σi*) for all σi.
that they committed the crime, so the two suspects are inter-
rogated at the same time in separate rooms. Four scenarios
Situations involving public goods often resemble the prisoners'
are possible depending on whether the suspects cooperate
dilemma. In a cluster the public good is a joint project, where
with the police or deny the crime. If they both deny, the police
the actors of the cluster can choose an effort level to contrib-
does not have evidence, so they must be released with minimal
ute to this project. While choosing a high effort would be bet-
charges for the illegal weapons. If they both cooperate, they
ter overall, the individual actors prefer to free-ride on others'
can be charged with the robbery, but get some reduction of
efforts and spend own resources on own projects ultimately
the prison sentence for their cooperation. If on the other hand
leading to the breakdown of the project and a dysfunctional
one of them cooperates and the other denies, the first is set
free for the cooperation while the other is put to jail for a long
sentence that is made even longer by the refusal to cooperate
In real life we do see public goods realised, and cooperation is
with the police. In the following table we present the game
often possible in similar prisoners' dilemmas. How can be res-
in normal form, in each case the first value is the utility of the
cue cooperation? A suitable legal framework using hefty fines
first suspect, the second is that of the second suspect in this
can change the payoffs so that shirking is not a best response.
outcome. A longer prison sentence is represented by a smaller
We return to this topic in the following section. As the legal
utility (a negative number with a larger absolute value).
framework is never perfect, the enforcement may come too
late, we may wish to look for self-enforcing mechanisms to
maintain cooperation.
1 To be precise these are the mixed strategies that include a randomisation over the so-called pure strategies
S.
If the interaction lasts for more the one encounter the utility
rather than the means to achieve these. At the same time the
from a decision must also include the utility from future
so-called Nash program works on showing that the very same
encounters. Mutual trust and mutual cooperation can be
results could be obtained as equilibria of non-cooperative
rewarded by future trust and cooperation. If the probability of
games. Put it simply: we can say that cooperative games are
future encounters is high and value of future money is high
result, non-cooperative games are method oriented.
(the inflation is not too high), it is less likely that a one-time
defection and the corresponding high payoff is greater than
In the following we introduce the basic ideas and terminology
the value of future cooperation.
of cooperative games.
Note that this value of future cooperation is only there if the
We still have a set of players and this set is denoted by
N. Sub-
game is played repeatedly forever or at least is repeated with
sets of this set, that is, groups of players are the
coalitions.
high probability. A cooperation with a definite or likely end
Actions, strategies are implicit and are limited to choosing play-
does not help: in the last period the cooperation breaks down
ers for cooperation. Instead of a utility function for individual
removing the incentives in the previous period to cooperate,
players, we have a value
V for each coalition (Figure 3).
The idea of this value function originates from von Neumann &
Morgenstern (1944) who determined this value assuming that
II.2 Cooperative
if a coalition
C forms the remaining players play
against this
coalition. Whatever
C is
guaranteed to make from this situation
The main difference between cooperative and non-cooperative
is its value. Now we simply give the value of each coalition.
games is that in cooperative games players can make bind-
If we also make the assumption that members of a coalition
ing agreements, i.e. agreements they must keep. In coopera-
can arbitrarily share this coalitional value then we talk about a
tive games the interest is on the formation of coalitions (see
game given in characteristic function form or simply a transfer-
Figure 2) and on the sharing of the benefits of cooperation
able utility (TU)-game.
2 In cooperative games strategies are limited to the choice of cooperation. In this example the player makes a choice between the "red" and the "green" coalitions – or staying with the ("blue") grand coalition.
3 The characteristic value of the "red" coalition is classically defined as the minimal value obtained when playing against the complementer coalition, that is, the coalition of the remaining players
What is the solution of such a cooperative game? In purely
For the sake of this example consider a cluster producing
cooperative games we assume that the grand coalition forms
and selling furniture. Some of the actors specialise in office,
where all players cooperate and the solution only specifies how
kitchen or children's furniture, others in marketing, logistics or
the players will distribute the value of the grand coalition. In
producing brass parts. It is natural to assume that the brass
some situations this assumption may be too restrictive. If, for
part manufacturers could form a (smaller) cluster themselves
instance we want to know if a group of regional companies
and share technology, buy and sell in large quantities etc. etc.
should form a cluster, we may also want to know if all these
such a cluster clearly has some potential benefits. Now suppose
companies have incentives to belong to the cluster. In such a
that the furniture cluster generates some extra profit thanks
case the problem is two-fold: which coalitions form, and how
to costs savings and extra trade generated. How to share this
do these coalitions share their values among their members.
extra profit?
For the moment we will focus on
games of pure cooperation.
An imputation is a distribution of the payoff of the grand coali-
Of course one should not imagine a pile of banknotes or a sum
tion among its members, such that each player gets at least
sitting on a bank account: the money is often of the forms
as much as it can get without cooperation, that is, as a single-
of cost savings that may be realised unevenly. If therefore the
player coalition.
brass manufacturers feel that they get less than what they
could make with the same facilities outside the present cluster,
As there are no strategies in these games, the equilibria defined
they might demand a higher share or threaten to leave the clus-
for non-cooperative games are of no use. There are at least
ter. The higher share of the extra profit is probably in the form
two types of solutions and two very popular solutions: the core
of higher prices in the contract for brass parts. Is this attractive
and the Shapley-value. Before we move on to a more formal
for the rest of the cluster? Well, the rest of the companies could
definition we provide the intuition of these concepts by means
also buy the parts from other sources. If the cluster is worth
of two simple stories.
more than its parts – it is superadditive – then an agreement
is always possible. Quite similarly, each group of actors: mer-
chants, kitchen makers, small companies, large companies, etc.
could – and should – consider its outside options. We say that
the allocation of the extra profits is in the core if all these com-
is not very favourable for A1: it practically must build the whole
panies find the allocation reasonable and they cannot – justifi-
mall with high costs, while A89 may incur no extra costs at all
ably demand an increase of its actors collective share.
despite a long list of special requirements – already satisfied
thanks to actors coming earlier. To make this fair we consider
For the second example consider a cluster of companies build-
all possible numbering of companies – there may be very many
ing and using a shopping mall. Different shops or groups of
such numberings – and take the average contribution.
shops might have different preferences. The luxury shops insist
on the marble pavement, the banks want to have high security
Academics widely consider these methods as acceptable ways
measures, the hypermarket an easily accessible shopping mall,
to share the profits and in fact such metods have been used
the cinema the late opening hours. Each of these demands in-
for building airport runways (sharing the costs among land-
crease the total cost of the project. The question is: how to
ing aircraft, (Littlechild & Thompson, 1977)) or managing the
share the profits when we know that the costs depend on the
Tennessee river (sharing the costs among nearby farms, ship-
actors' wishes. One possible method is to use the core again,
ping companies, and cities in the Tennessee Valley (Straffin &
but in this setting the Shapley value is more natural. For this
Heaney, 1981)) among others. In the rest of the section we
number the actors as A1, A2, etc. First assume that only A1
present a short technical summary of these two concepts. This
builds and operates the mall. The costs will obviously be lower,
section may safely be skipped, this will not hamper the under-
but so will be the profits. The difference (possibly negative: a
standing of our paper.
loss) is what A1 could obtain on its own Now take A2 and see
what does it add. The two companies need a somewhat bigger
The
core (Gillies, 1959) is the cooperative equivalent of the
mall, may attract more customers, so we can again calculate
Nash equilibrium, but it allows also for coalitional deviations
the value for the two-company mall. The contribution of A2 is
(Figure 4). The core collects imputations such that for all coa-
the increase of the profit with respect to the single-company
litions it holds that the total payoff paid to members of this
mall. Note this amount next to A2's name. And so on for A3,
coalition are equal to or higher than the value of the coalition.
A4, etc. This row of numbers tells us how much each of these
Were this not true, the coalition would not sign the agreement,
companies added to the value of the project. Clearly, this order
but rather operate on its own. While it may seem rather dif-
4 In the core no coalition of players benefits from forming and leaving the cooperation.
5 The Shapley-value takes the average marginal contribution of a player. For this all possible orders in which a coalition may have grown are considered.
6 A coalition has no structure
7 There may be many different network structures supporting the same coalition. Networks a), b) and c) all support the coalition in Figure 1, while network d) is disconnected and therefore cannot support the same coalition.
ficult to satisfy the demands of all coalitions most games have
A whole stream of literature has been motivated by the poten-
many imputations that satisfy them. Unfortunately there are
tial emptiness of the core either to see what happens in the
also many that do not have any. We say that the core of such
game if the core is empty or to somehow save cooperation. For
games is
empty. So-called
balanced games have non-empty
instance the minimal dominant set (Kóczy & Lauwers, 2007)
cores (Bondareva, 1963; Shapley, 1967). To have an empty core
contains imputations that emerge dynamically after playing the
means that the total resources available to the grand coalition
game for long. Approximate cores (Shubik & Wooders, 1983)
are not sufficient to simultaneously satisfy the coalitional de-
take the costs of forming/breaking agreements into account:
when these costs are high, higher than the gains from leaving
the grand coalition, cooperation survives.
The sharing aspect of imputations is better expressed by the
Shapley-value (Shapley, 1953), that pays the marginal contribu-
tion to each player. It can be best understood by a story: Initially
Coalitions are a greately simplified version of reality as they lack
the first player has its own value as a single player coalition
internal structure (Figure 6). In some situations the structure
.The the second player arrives and it contributes the difference
of cooperation has a role, too. Where personal connections
between the value of this duo and the first player's single player
or trust play a role only cooperation between parties that are
coalition, and so on (Figure 5). We then take all the
n! possible
connected to each other personally or who trust each other are
orderings of the players and take the average of a player's mar-
possible. In such situations a player can have a high value simply
ginal contributions.
for connecting other, productive players (Borm, Owen, & Tijs,
1992; Herings, van der Laan, & Talman, 2005). The core can
The Shapley value is never empty, it is always defined. (Dubey,
also be generalised to games where the connections among
1975; Neyman, 1989; Shapley, 1953) and others have shown
the players are important. For such TU games over a network
that the Shapley value determines the only way to divide the
we must have a value function and know the underlying net-
total coalitional value if we require some simple, often elemen-
work of players.
tary properties, such as symmetry, to hold. The Shapley value
gives a fair way to share the coalitional payoff, but it is not
In network games only coalitions that are connected make sense
always a stable way. The Shapley-value belongs to the core in
(Figures 7a-c and 8a). A disconnected coalition (Figures 7d and
so-called convex games (Shapley, 1971), but it may well be that
8b) means that some of its members cannot communicate and
the core is not empty, but the Shapley value is outside the core.
therefore coordinate. Such a coalition then clearly cannot form.
In such games the allocation that is considered fair is simply not
accepted by all coalitions.
a) Feasible coalition
b) Infeasible coalition
8 Coalitions under network 2a. The coalition in Figure 3a is connected, while Figure 3b is not. Members of the coalition on 3b cannot communicate and are therefore not a threat.
III Cluster
By now it may be clear that game theory, especially cooperative
ural choice. Since the participating companies and institutions
game theory, models conflict situations very similar to those
are naturally interpreted as players the question that remains
that can arise in a cluster. Over the decades researchers have
is how to find the coalitional values, that is, the characteristic
written hundreds, possibly thousands of papers researching
function. In other words: what is the value of a coalition?
these games, providing ways to "solve" these games, that is,
acceptable ways to solve the conflict among the players as well
We see two possible interpretations: (1) Projects as coalitions
as describing properties of these games that guarantee, for
(Figure 9) or (2) Clusters as coalitions (Figure 11).
instance, that a conflict can be a win-win situation.
In the following we formalise the connection between coop-
III.1 Where are the coalitions in
erative, so-called TU games and clusters making it possible to
use the enormous literature written for games to be used in
the study of clusters. The ultimate purpose of this exercise is
Projects as coalitions/coalitions as projects
to translate the game theoretic properties into golden rules for
cluster evaluation.
A project is a form of cooperation among actors of a cluster
that has a clear project plan, project objectives and an estimat-
Our aim is to evaluate clusters by game theoretic means. This
ed project profit. This project profit is the value of the coalition.
requires first the translation of the problem into a mathematical
What are the advantages or disadvantages of this approach?
format, solve the problem using game theoretic methods and
translate back the results into practical recommendations.
The single most important aspect of a project is that it is
something specific, material and therefore the profitability of
We are interested in the possibility and nature of cooperation in
a project is a natural question, something that is also raised
clusters, so modelling clusters by cooperative games is the nat-
by the participants already before joining the project. On the
Projects as coalition
9 Projects as coalitions
10 Balanced collection: The members of the blue coalition are committed to it, while the members of the purple coalitions share their time between two such coalitions each.
other hand we do not only look at the behaviour of a cluster in
Clusters as coalitions/coalitions as clusters
the present, but would also like to understand future contin-
gencies. For that we would need information about future or
In general a cluster is not created for a single project nor for a
even potential projects. For such projects the same information
small set of projects but rather to be an incubator for new ideas
is not available or is not accurate. In a cluster it is perfectly natu-
ral that a cluster actor will participate in multiple projects and
share its time among these activities. This behaviour is not nat-
Basing our calculations on current projects only can be very lim-
ural in cooperative games, coalitions do not generally overlap.
ited and may only be indicative of the minimal potential of the
cluster. So instead, we see a coalition as a cluster, possibly with
Overlapping projects can be modelled by so-called (balanced)
some ongoing projects, but also with the potential for new
collections (Figure 10). In a balanced collection each player
projects. The value of a coalition is then the present value of all
spends the same amount of time on the projects including pos-
future profits coming from the projects from within the group.
sibly a project that does not involve other players. The limita-
This value is comparable to the value of a stock that is also seen
tion of this setting is in the assumption that a project requires
as the present value of the future stream of dividends.
the simultaneous cooperation of the players, in other words,
actors of a particular project/coalition must spend the same
This second concept is much more general. While it clearly
amount of time on that project/in that coalition. This is clearly
includes the value of a project if the set of participants coin-
a restrictive assumption that will not typically hold in a natural
cides with the coalition, it also allows for other projects by sub-
sets of the coalition members. As a special case it includes the
profit from singleton projects, that is, from projects that do not
need cooperation with other players. On the other hand it does
not include the profit of projects that require cooperation with
outsiders. The complexity of this approach is also its disadvan-
Clusters as coalitions
11 Clusters as coalitions
tage. Just as there may be disagreements about the value of
whether the fundamental assumptions of game theory also
a stock, the value of such a cluster-coalition is also difficult to
hold in the setting of industrial clusters.
determine. Especially that the definition of the game requires
an exponential number of such valuations.
In the following we outline a set of questions and hypotheses
corresponding to these basic assumptions. If these hypotheses
are tested to be valid, a rather standard game theoretic approach
III.2 About translating clusters into
can be used. If some are found false we may still use the model,
but with certain modifications. If many of these assumptions
are false, new richer models need to be developed. We must
Game theory is a branch of mathematics with widespread
note that this is a very unlikely case and once again point at the
applications in business and economics as well as many other
numerous applications where the game theoretic approach has
disciplines from biology to politics. Being a theoretical science
already proved itself useful.
its models live not even in sterile laboratories, but in the ide-
alised realm of sets and factorials and Greek letters. Real Life
In the first group of hypotheses we focus on the fundamentals.
must surely be more complicated! Has such a model anything
to do with reality?
As a first prerequisite we would like to understand what drives
clusters, what drives the formation of clusters. We depart
We believe, it does. In fact, it is not only us, but the ocean of
from the usual principal-agent approach where the conflict is
working applications prove that on the one hand people, but
between the owners and the managers of a company as clus-
especially companies can very well be modelled by the homo
ter actors are often too small, owners are often the managers
oeconomicus, the selfish man and on the other, that game the-
as well. We expect the dichotomy to lie between the profit
ory is flexible enough to accommodate small deviations from
or value maximising totally rational faceless investor and the
the standard setups. Is this also the case for clusters? While we
entrepreneur who is driven by creativity, by the joy of creating
are quite optimistic, one has to carefully check and investigate
something new and the joy of collaborating with others. We
do not say that the two aspects cannot live along each other,
and organisations. Several companies and research groups are
but before going any further we must understand if the cluster
in the race to come up with the first working model. While
is a means to reach a higher profit level, to collect previously
there is a lot of uncertainty in the patent race, three things are
unrealised profit or it is perhaps the goal itself.
clear: the company that can file the patents first takes most of
the market, the rest may have spent large amounts of money
The motivation for this question is clear. While some clusters
on the research, but most of this has just been wasted, and
kick off with intense co operation, with very clear goals and
money can accelerate the research process. So if you put in
objectives, there are clusters founded by friends and schoolmates
more money, you are more likely to win, but if you lose never-
with the aim of co-operation with old acquaintances hoping
theless, you lose more.
that something useful comes out of it – and in the meantime
the collaboration is fun, all will enjoy business lunches.
This is a lot like the dollar-auction, where a 100-dollar bill is
auctioned away, but with the catch that all bids, including los-
The formation of clusters is supported by national and EU insti-
ing bids, must be paid. Here the prize is the profit made with
tutions. In extreme cases obtaining this support can be the goal
the product, while the bids are the research costs. Once one
itself. Naturally all clusters must have a project, such clusters
enters the dollar auction, it is difficult to stop. The difference
have such projects, too, but the realisation would be possible
between a winning and a losing bid is just a few dollars so if
without the formation of the cluster. Such a cluster is clearly
we compare this with the prize, it is surely worth putting it in. If
about money, so it clearly belongs to the first group, where the
all actors think this way, however, the bids can go way beyond
aim is maximising profits, and the national or EU support is just
the 100 dollar figure – we may see this in the research game,
one way to realise this.
too: Once in the patent race companies try to avoid being a
close second either by quitting the game early or by outbidding
A company is approached by another company to do a joint
the others.
project. The offer covers all project-related costs (including
standard profit rates to satisfy investors) plus 1% of the remain-
Our interest in these issues is twofold. On the one hand – relat-
ing profit. Rationally the company should accept the offer since
ed to hypothesis 1 – we would like to understand what drives
every bit of extra profit is great. In practice, however, the com-
cluster actors, what are their objectives. On the other hand, in
pany may be offended by the small share and ask for more or
order to use mainstream economic and game theoretic models
reject it. This example of an ultimatum game illustrates that
we must have companies that are rational (in an economic, that
economic rationality cannot be taken for granted.
is: homo oeconomicus sense), companies that work on maxi-
mising their profits and make well-informed decisions with this
Hypothesis 1. Companies join clusters as a homo oeco-
nomicus, with the intention to harvest profits that
could not be harvested otherwise. Other factors, such
If our hypothesis is false, not all is lost, but a formal analysis of
as the joy of creativity and collaboration facilitates this
strategic decision making would require more complex math-
co-operation but only play an auxiliary role and can be
ematical apparatus.
expressed in financial terms.
Hypothesis 2. Companies take conscious decisions when
joining clusters and this decision is just as formal as the
III.3 The bases of decision making:
decisions when joining any other co-operation.
Do actors like profi t?
So what are the pros and cons of joining a cluster. On the one
Irrespective of the answer to the first hypothesis we would
hand actors of a cluster expect profits from projects that would
like to understand the mechanisms that result in a company or
not realise otherwise or from economies of scale or scope real-
other legal entity joining a cluster. We would like to know to
ised through the cluster. What are the costs on the other hand?
what extent can these mechanisms be considered as formal.
The costs of running a cluster initiative or cluster organisation
Do companies use formal protocols before such a decision is
are not substantial when compared to the possible benefits.
Even if all these costs are for nothing, the losses are not severe
so however small the probability of realising the foreseeable
The next generation solar panel will be a massive hit: govern-
profits is the benefits outweigh the direct costs. There are how-
ments provide better and better incentives to reduce energy
ever other costs, too. A cluster can only become an incubator
usage, and on the other hand their high efficiency might mean
for new projects if the actors share confidential business infor-
that installing them will be a profitable decision for many homes
mation. The cost here is sharing this information.
One thing that is not clear is how deep the economic analysis of
As a technical detail we would like to understand how compa-
these companies is. Consider a company making funny T-shirts.
nies handle future profit streams. Two aspects are considered.
Creativity is costless so the price of such a T-shirt is really just
First: the possible sources of income. Clusters are there not
the cost of the T-shirt (for simplicity we say this is 0) plus an
only to create a formal environment for current projects and
arbitrary markup for the creative design. Suppose this markup
co-operations, but as an incubator for future ideas, for future
is somewhere in the range 1 … 00. The company knows that
projects. In fact, clusters are not needed to complete ongoing
there are many similar shirt-makers around, and they will lose
projects. Do companies understand this difference and include
customers unless they sell significantly below the average price,
future projects in their cost-benefit analysis?
but make as much money as possible. Say, around half of the
average price of similar funny T-shirts. How much should it
Hypothesis 4. Cluster actors attach value to projects in
value its creativity? What should we say?
the cluster that are not yet realised.
This is a well-known game that has been asked at various audi-
How is this value estimated? On the one hand companies have
ences, but the patterns are always the same. There are some
difficulties even to estimate the value of current projects, how
fifties, twenty-fives, … ones. What is the good answer? Let us
could they have estimates the value of projects they do not
say right now that the correct answer is very difficult, as we
even know who are they with or what will the contents be.
will see it from the following argument. The naive company
Such detailed information is difficult to obtain and are super-
will just say: we have no info about other prices yet, so we
ficial. We would, on the other hand understand the long-term
might as well choose any number. This is the level-0 argument.
expectations of cluster actors: do they expect similar profits
The level-1 argument is a little more sophisticated: Since no
from their cluster participation even after the current projects
T-shirt can be more expensive than $100, if we want to be
have expired or beyond the current projects? Do they expect
among the cheaper half, we should never say more than fifty.
less or more? How much less or more? It is important to stress
Those saying fifty probably think level-1. The level-2 argument
that we do not need to check the validity of these estimates,
goes further. Since nobody will sell for more than $50, we can
we only need to understand the information that the compa-
only be much cheaper than the average if we do not sell for
nies base their cost-benefit analysis on.
more than $25. But then the argument can be repeated and
the level 3–4–5– … arguments claim that one should never sell
The profit from (present or) future projects does not come at
for more than (rounding the numbers) 13, 7, 4, 2, … 1. If all
the time of the investment. How is this profit stream aggre-
the companies are fully rational one can only remain competi-
gated so that it becomes comparable to the costs that occur
tive if the price is 1. Is this the best way to make profit? Is this
at the time of the decision? (We realise the future projects will
how the company makes the most profit? Most likely not. The
require project-specific investments that are subtracted from
company choosing this price is clever enough to make such a
the incomes realised at the same time; the profit is the differ-
high-level argument, but fails to realise that not all companies
ence of the two that can at times be negative.).
are equally sophisticated. A sophisticated company will realise
not only that the argument does not stop at 50, but also that
We consider two possible scenarios. Companies base their
some other companies do not go further. For an accurate an-
decisions on predictions for a finite horizon, such as for the
swer we must think how sophisticated our competitors may be.
coming 3–5 years. For this limited horizon it is still possible to
This depends on the composition of the decision makers, but
make relatively accurate predictions based on data and models
for a general crowd 12 may approximately be a good answer
used for "standard" business plans. Longer estimations require
(so long as not too many people read this text).
additional data and perhaps more refined models, the cost of
which outweighs the increased accuracy of predictions.
This example illustrates the importance of understanding how
sophisticated the actors are. While such a detailed analysis is
Ideally, however, and this is the second option, the present
not necessary a number of simple hypotheses clarify the basic
value of an infinite income stream should be considered with
appropriate discounting. This approach is not only useful math-
ematically, but is –theoretically- the common practice to cal-
Hypothesis 3. Companies do a cost-benefit analysis com-
culate the value of a company with publicly held shares or of
paring the cost of sharing confidential information with
a real estate. The difficulty lies not only in the estimation of
other cluster actors and the foreseeable benefits from
future profits, but also in determining the discount factors. The
discount factor can incorporate, besides the devaluation of cur-
rency also the decreasing probability that the cluster will exist
or that the company is still part of the cluster.
In practice we expect a compromise between the two
The first thing we note is that such a code is essentially about
approaches limiting a horizon, but discounting future profits.
the distribution of the profits of the cluster. While the code can
How do companies treat future profit streams?
specify property rights or hierarchies these all have monetary
values and can be expressed as payoffs. This is especially true
Hypothesis 5. The value of a cluster for a particular com-
for the allocation of such rights or duties when applied to
pany is discounted money-stream within a given time
future contingencies.
horizon with a discounting reflecting the depreciation
of the currency as well as the probability that the project
In our first hypotheses in this section we look at the nature of
or stream of projects will be discontinued.
cluster codes. We believe that a project does not start until pay-
offs are specified for all contingencies. This really means two
Given our hypotheses about the way companies make deci-
things: firstly, that companies, when starting a project, realise
sions about clusters we can move on to the decisions about
the possible alternative project outcomes. Put it simply: they
forming a cluster. Some of our hypotheses will likely be false:
realise that the project can be failure producing a loss, a success
this will influence our models to some extent, but, as we
producing a profit, it can be a huge success producing a profit
have indicated earlier already, this does not normally turn our
beyond expectations and at last it may create a benefit even
approach invalid.
success, but different from the expectations. Does the code
specifiy contingencies for all possible outcomes?
III.4 Cluster code – structure:
Hypothesis 6. The cluster code addresses alternative out-
Do actors think about present
and future alternatives?
Note that the alternative outcomes may be due to external, but
also internal circumstances or events.
In the following we state a number of hypotheses about the
cluster code. Some clusters do not have a formal
contract, but
It is also important that the code does not only recognise the
operate more on a club-like basis. In such a case by contract
alternative outcomes, but that it provides rules for allocating
we mean a collection of formal and informal agreements that
profits (or losses) for all possible states of the world (up to rel-
are nevertheless commonly known to the actors of the cluster.
evance to the cluster). Do actors consider "unlikely" events
In the code we also include the general framework support-
when making decisions?
ing the writing of contracts for projects that do not include
all actors of the cluster. Such a framework does not only pro-
Hypothesis 7. The cluster code specifies contingencies
vide a possible legal aid, but outlines the general principles of
for off-equilibrium or non-ideal outcomes too.
the cluster. These principles determine not only the current
contracts related to current projects, but form the basis for
Let us stress the importance of Hypothesis 7: If this Hypothesis
future contracts related to future projects. In sum, by cluster
is not true profit-seeking companies might join a seemingly –
code we do not necessarily mean a written, legal code, but the
for them – disadvantageous cluster expecting a different out-
de facto standards of behaviour regarding present and future
come that, on the other hand, is favourable to them. Instead,
agreements. We must underline the crucial role of the cluster
companies must see clusters as a full package, making a deci-
manager in creating and – in the absence of a legal document
sion that is rational regarding the entirety of the code.
addressing all issues below – maintaining and enforcing this
Setting the golden rules
IV Setting the golden rules
Having clarified the basic framework for decision making and
Hypothesis 8. A company only joins a cluster if this brings
having thereby made the connection to game theory we can
now move on to discuss the cooperation-related decisions a
cluster actor company must make. Understanding the incen-
While some of the well-known clusters overseas have emerged
tives of the individual companies we can discuss properties
in an organic way, in Europe it is common to expedite the pro-
of the cluster they constitute. In particular we may be able to
cess with a top-down approach, "creating" a cluster. While
translate game theoretic concepts into golden rules of cluster
we do not want to speculate on the particulars of this pro-
evaluation. As an ultimate goal our model could produce quan-
cess there will be a point when a company makes a decision
titative predictions about a cluster's expected performance or
whether to join a particular cluster and at this point the cluster
is either already existing, or is already forming, but already in
this latter case the scope of cooperation, the possibilities for
joint projects as well as some of the cluster code is known. In
IV.1 Joining a cluster: Do actors
sum, the company has some information – however vague – on
the prospects with this cluster.
look for profi t?
Now that the structure of the cluster code, directly or indirectly
Given that joining a cluster involves some costs, too, one
specifying payoffs in all world states is given we can move on
should normally investigate other alternatives. For the moment
to the strategic decisions of the companies.
suppose that a company has the possibility of joining one of
two clusters. Of course it should join the one that brings higher
The first property, Hypothesis 8 is very natural. This corre-
sponds to individual rationality in game theory and is a usual
precondition for solution concepts.
12 Only join a coalition for extra profit
13 Choose the more profitable cluster
Hypothesis 9. If a company has the possibility to join one
a more general condition regarding the choice among multiple
of two clusters the company will join the one that results
in higher payoffs.
Hypothesis 10. A company should join the most profit-
Note that in general companies may join more than one cluster
able of all available clusters.
and sometimes they do, but this is rare for companies with a
profile corresponding to the main profile of the company.
This property is known as coalitional rationality. It has two
direct implications that are corollaries of this hypothesis, but,
So far our hypotheses are hardly more than concompanyations
to be more explicit about these, we state them as separate
of standard assumptions or perhaps some elements of a deci-
sion making process formalised into a statement. Hypotheses
in the following are far less obvious and while the statements
Hypothesis 10a. A company should leave the cluster if a
are stated as hypotheses, we do not expect that all will be
more attractive participation offer becomes available in
accepted. In any case, we must note that if some of these
another cluster.
hypotheses are rejected that can, in itself, have severe conse-
quences for the behaviour of the cluster.
The word "leave" is to be used with care: being an actor of a
cluster means that there are rights and obligations. The code
In the aforementioned scenario, where clusters are created in
of the cluster, by Hypothesis 7 specifies these for the event of
a top-down approach companies rarely have possibility to con-
departure, too. Once joined the cluster, a company must take
sider joining more than one cluster. A typical company will be
the possible punishments into account when contemplating on
invited to some meeting with the prospect of joining a cluster
the departure. The more common use of "leave" – and this is
whose code is either already clear or is shaping up. Yet, a
our understanding – is before joining the cluster, so it is more
rational company should, before joining a cluster, do a full anal-
about leaving the negotiations. Here no commitment has yet
ysis of its options. By Hypothesis 8 it should only join a cluster
been made, so a company will naturally be attracted by the
that brings additional benefits. The following statement adds
more advantageous terms.
Setting the golden rules
This is also true if the better offer comes from within the clus-
As a minimal requirement the cluster must be more valuable
ter. Indeed, most clusters have far more actors than a typical
than its parts put together (superadditivity at the top level is
project requires and therefore a cluster consisting of only part
called
cohesiveness), but, as we will see this is not sufficient,
of the actors of the original cluster (for a clear distinction we call
the game defined from the problem must also be
balanced
the smaller cluster
subcluster) would typically be a profitable
(Bondareva, 1963; Shapley, 1967). First we state a natural con-
cluster, too. While one often thinks that the whole is more than
dition that corresponds to
coalitional rationality in game theory
the two parts, crowding effects or the higher costs of manag-
and that defines the
core.
ing a larger organisation creates real life situations where the
part may be more successful.2 In game theoretic terms we say
Hypothesis 11. The code of a cluster ensures that the
that the game is not necessarily
superadditive, that is, adding
gain of any subcluster exceeds its profit as an independ-
up parts does not necessarily create additional value.
ent cluster.
Hypothesis 10b. A company only joins a cluster if none of
A few notes regarding this hypothesis. Firstly, it is important
the subclusters offer better prospects.
to emphasize that a subcluster does not need to secede or
even organise itself to start a protest to get its share. Getting
as much as it can obtain on its own is a right that must be
IV.2 Cluster code: How to keep all
respected by all parties to facilitate cooperation. This is a bit like
a seat on an airplane: it is very rare that someone else takes our
cluster actors happy at the
seat as such an action would usually lead to a conflict where he
same time?
or she must give up the seat anyway. The same holds here. No
fights are required as the rights are respected. A good cluster
In section IV.3 we have looked at the structure or "shape" of
manager can ensure that the allocation of the profits is such
the cluster code. Now that the basis on which the companies
that the conflict will never arise. To do this the cluster manager
joining decisions are made have been clarified we return to
must be very familiar with the companies' potentials for coop-
the cluster code, more precisely the distribution of the cluster
Secondly this innocent condition is actually a family of a huge
It is clear that there is no point in setting up a code that is
number of conditions for a typical sized cluster. The number of
not acceptable to the actors. If the cluster cannot provide bet-
possible subclusters grows exponentially with the number of
ter prospects than other clusters or its subclusters, some of its
cluster actors: the addition of a single cluster actor doubles the
foreseen actors will not join.
number of conditions. Can so many, to a great extent conflict-
ing conditions be simultaneously satisfied? Clearly, if the overall
We must handle two problems (corresponding to Hypotheses
gains are less than the total gains of some non-overlapping
10a and 10b) separately:
External threats are somewhat more
subclusters (a partition of the cluster actors) this is not possible.
difficult to study as the threat is often not even on the map,
Unfortunately there are cases when the gains of the cluster by
but on the other hand the general industrial organisation (IO)
far exceed the gains of such non-overlapping subclusters and
literature already addresses the issues of competition between
still the ideal, stable allocation of the cluster profit is not pos-
companies. The competition for a particular cluster actor is, to
sible, or in game theoretic terms: the core is empty.
a great extent an issue of competition among substitutes, that
is, companies that offer similar products or services. In our con-
Even if the core is non-empty not all allocations are ideal. Can
text the complementarity comes in the form of clusters being
such a cluster be saved from falling apart? The good news is
able to cooperate and produce profits with a given company.
that it can be. A series of carefully orchestrated changes in the
code of the cluster will always lead to a stable allocation (a so-
In the following we look at the
internal threats, that is, internal
called imputation in the core), moreover the number of such
conflicts of interests that may destabilise the cluster. Ultimately
changes is only proportional with the number of cluster actors
we want to understand what makes a cluster stable against
and not the conditions in Hypothesis 11 (Béal, Durieu, & Solal,
such destabilising forces.
2008; Béal, Rémila, & Solal, 2010; Kóczy, 2006; Kóczy & Lauw-
ers, 2004; Yang, 2010).
2 Let us already indicate distribuitional effects too: the whole may be more than the parts, but if the gains cannot be distributed in a mutually satisfactory
way cooperation may break down.
IV.3 Social networks: How do
Hypothesis 12. A (sub)cluster must be connected: Any
other actor must be a friend's friend's … friend.
The expression "social network" is now widely associated with
We realise that a cluster may also be successful as a club in
Web 2.0 sites and especially social networking sites. When we
helping actors to new acquaintances this being possibly the
think of social networks and business we tend to associate to
most direct way to obtain more than the parts put together.
new websites – the development of the world wide web into
We do not want to underplay the importance of new friend-
this direction has very quickly dominated the original concept
ships, but due to their uncertainty (we do not know who will be
of social networks. While today we tend to see social networks
our next friend, even), the companies' decisions in joining one
as a way teenagers waste their youth although
networking
or another cluster cannot be made on the basis of these pos-
came way before the social networking sites or even the whole
sible connections. Once these possible connections are realised
the network of connections must be redrawn.
Networking is to build contacts for a possible future coopera-
If Hypothesis 12 is found to be true we must slightly modify the
tion. Indeed, a cooperation is only possible if the parties know
evaluation of the cluster. Not all subclusters can form, rather:
each other. Of course we do not talk about cooperation that is
typically most cannot form as most are not connected. We can
limited to putting together a product of the parts some cluster
still consider our previous model, where the connections are
actors produce, but of projects where know-how, experience
ignored by simply setting the value of impossible subclusters
and business ideas are shared to achieve a better product. The
to zero making them unattractive. In other words, actors of
underlying social or communication network also determines
impossible clusters will never be unsatisfied as a group about
the cooperation possibilities for the cluster. Only connected
the allocation of profits in a cluster. With this change the very
projects are possible: projects where any two participants
same approach can be used as when the network of connec-
can be connected by a series of acquaintances. It is natural to
tions is ignored.
extend this idea to clusters and subclusters: if a cluster consists
of more than one component that are not connected to each
other no joint projects will be possible, so having these compo-
nents in a common cluster does not bring additional benefits.
Hypothesis testing
V Hypothesis
We have stated a dozen hypotheses about the way clusters
As a simple example consider the so-called
ultimatum game.
operate (Hypotheses 1–12). In Section I we have given an
This game is about sharing a fixed sum, such as €100. The first
extensive overview of the literature of cluster evaluation. One
player can propose a division, the second player can either
would rightly expect that such an amount of literature will
accept or reject this. If the second player accepts, the division
answer some of our points. Our approach is, however rather
is final and the players get the corresponding sums as payoffs.
novel focusing on the individual companies' incentives and
If the second player rejects, the players get nothing. A rational
decision making mechanisms that are quite different from the
second player focussing only on the payoffs should always
usual data that are more statistical in nature.
accept the proposal, even if she is only offered €1 as this is still
more than nothing. In a laboratory the parties are randomly
We have made every effort to answer these questions using
matched out of the 12–20 participants so that the first player
our expertise in clusters and in game theory, but in the absence
cannot be identified (and also the first player does not know
of an empirical investigation our conclusions remain just specu-
the identity of the second player) and therefore personal ties,
lations. In the following, however we outline how the missing
reputational issues should not play a role. In practice, however
information could be obtained.
such an offer is rarely accepted, even offers close to the 50–
50 distribution are sometimes turned down suggesting that
second players are willing to incur costs in punishing in what
V.1 Fundamentals of decision
they see as a deviant behaviour. Interestingly, a series of ex-
periments have found that cultural aspects play a crucial role in
determining what an acceptable proposal is: in cultures with a
We must, first of all understand if the cluster actors make
high degree of self reliance only little transfer is expected, while
decisions along the rationality principles we have outlined in
in societies where cooperation is essential for survival players
the first set of hypotheses (Hypotheses 1–7). This requires a
may allow only a smaller share to be kept by the proposer.
detailed insight into the decision mechanisms of cluster actors
as well as the organisation and code of the cluster. We see two
The ultimatum game is, of course, just a simple example, but
methods to collect such information.
such simple games give us information about the way partici-
pants make their decisions. Of course hundreds of experiments
Firstly we need to conduct
interviews with the cluster actors'
have already been conducted, but these experiments typically
decision makers and the cluster manager. The interviews would
involve undergraduate economics students with fresh memo-
follow a formal protocol, and with the help of economic psy-
ries of their game theory courses. The main reason for this is
chologists the answers would be collected in an indirect way.
that research is typically conducted at universities where stu-
Direct questions would not necessarily result in answers cor-
dents are – thanks to the financial compensation – readily avail-
responding to the reality: when asked, whether they make sen-
able. The second is that research budgets are always too tight
sible, economically well-founded decision mechanisms compa-
so that the financial compensation offered in an experiment is
nies would be inclined to say yes even if this is not the case just
less attractive to businessmen. This of course limits the applica-
to draw a better image of themselves.
bility of those experimental results to our hypotheses requiring
new experiments.
Out second method would draw on the methods of experi-
mental economists. We would like to conduct simple laborato-
ry experiments to find out the motives of the decision makers.
V.2 Profi tability
An economic experiment is conducted in a computer labora-
tory consisting of a server and a collection of workstations.
While the questionnaires and experiments help us to gain gen-
Participants make decisions using this computer interface, and
eral information about decision making in clusters, the second
depending on the participants' decisions the rules of the game
group of data is cluster-specific. Ideally we would like to have
determine the individual payoffs. This setup has been intro-
a figure for the cluster and all its subclusters that describe its
duced relatively recently and it is only the last few years that
profitability. This is an enormous amount of information that
experimental economics grew into a fully recognised discipline.
are not only sensitive data, but most likely this information is
One of the reasons might be that the results are often surpris-
not at all available. In practice we do not need precise data, we
ing, demonstrating that culture and morals.
need the profitability of the different subclusters, as perceived
by the potential actors. In other words, we do not need to
conduct extensive economic analyses for all the (exponential
At last, one may resort to questionnaires and interviews asking
number of) subclusters, but only approximate figures, as seen
about business partners, although such "soft" information is
by the companies.
more likely to be imprecise and incomplete and companies are
likely to be reluctant to share such valuable information.
We are considering several possible methods to obtain relevant
data realising that the cluster actors may or may not be too
keen to spend time on such studies, but the details are still
V.4 Conclusions on the data
open for further research.
Our aim is to study the micro-level incentives and therefore we
need micro-level data. The incentives we uncover determine
V.3 Networks
the internal stability of the cluster. The quantity and nature of
the data needed for the game-theoretic analysis is therefore
At last, for an analysis that takes the social or economic net-
quite different from the usual benchmark-based evaluation of
work within the cluster into account, we must have information
clusters. This does not necessarily mean that we must throw
about such links. We see 3 ways to gather such data. Firstly,
away single-number parameters. Once we get a deeper under-
when trying to obtain the value of subclusters, their actors
standing of, for instance, the usual structure of the network of
might simply respond that they do not know these people and
connections within a cluster, we can simulate similar networks
therefore cannot give an estimate of the value or profitability
and discover correspondences between the size of the cluster
of that cluster. In practice, however, it is unlikely that such
in terms of actors, the number of "friends" the average actor
detailed information is available, the value of the clusters must
has. On the other hand there may be a (negative) correlation
be estimated in some other way, which takes us to the other
between the number of friends for the average actor and the
geographical dispersion of the cluster. Unfortunately, to make
use of such, readily available indicators one has to explore the
A well-managed cluster is likely to have detailed and well doc-
relations with the more detailed data.
umented information about past instances of cooperation as
well as past business transactions. It may also have informa-
tion on how the various cluster actors got involved, perhaps
via other cluster actors. This is "hard" information on business
relations and is informative not only about the existence of eco-
nomic links, but also the intensity of these links.
Conclusion
What does the game theoretic approach contribute to the
For policy makers and organisations in some form or other
understanding of clusters? In economics game theory has
interested in cluster support giving them more clear picture
brought a complete renewal beginning in the 1950s. While
about the operation and risks of the cluster operation which
earlier models focussed on profit maximisation and other –
helps to subsidize the clusters' development more effective and
otherwise valid – arguments, ignored the obvious fact, namely
that the interactions are, after all, driven by the individual actors,
players, who will play according to the rules and incentives.
We do believe that the game theory can seriously influence the
By understanding the incentives of the individuals better we
research regarding clusters, networks and other co-operations
understand the nature of interactions: in this case the efforts
among companies. We must admit that in using our game the-
put into the cluster better.
oretic approach for real-life clusters might have some practical
difficulties might arise. We believe that these difficulties may
Our model is not omnipotent. Just as microeconomics must
be overcome and the benefit is a model that could show us the
use demand and production functions we also need a lot of
best way to maximize the outcome of our all investment as a
information and game theory cannot tell the prospects of a
cooperation. Whether a product is good or bad, or how the
economic climate might change in the near future are ques-
tions that are beyond our model.
But after testing of the hypotheses our model will present the
possibility to identify such kind of regularity which will help
all the cluster actors (policy makers, cluster managers, cluster
actors …) to recognize better and sooner not only the risks
regarding cluster operation but the methods how we can
reduce these risks as well. We do hope that with the help of the
game theory the cluster actors after weighing the opportunities
up will be able to make rational decisions.
Our results will be also useful for training cluster managers so
that the cluster manager him/herself shall help the operation
of the cluster as a real "quizmaster" to reduce the recognizable
risks, to initiate new projects, to support the implementation of
the projects and last but not least to increase the "value" of the
cluster in the actors' eyes.
They will also be useful for training cluster actors so that they
will be ready to make a rational evaluation on one hand on
their own value among the cluster actors cooperating in the
cluster organisation and on the other hand on the cluster
actors as well. They get to know the motives for the real co-oper-
ation and they can prepare themselves for the risks too. Being
in possession of this information they will be able to make an
established decision on what is the cluster worth and how they
can use the co-operation within the cluster to increase their
Boekholt, P. (1997). Innovative Networks in Regional Econo-
Fukuyama, F. (1995).
Trust: Social Virtues and the Creation of
mies: Enhancing Infrastructures for Technology Crea-
Prosperity. New York: The Free Press.
tion and Transfer. In J. Mitra & P. Formica (Eds.),
Innova-
tion and Economic Development, University-Enterprise
Fukuyama, F. (1999).
The Great disruption: Human Nature
Partnerships in Action (pp. 119–137). Dublin: Oak Tree
and the Reconstitution of Social Order. London: Profile
Bondareva, O. N. (1963). Some Applications of Linear Program-
Gillies, D. B. (1959). Solutions to general non-zero-sum games.
ming Methods to the Theory of Cooperative Games.
In A. W. Tucker & R. D. Luce (Eds.),
Contributions to the
Problemy Kybernetiki,
10, 119–139.
Theory of Games (Vol. IV, pp. 47–85). Princeton: Princ-
eton University Press.
Borm, P., Owen, G., & Tijs, S. (1992). On the Position Value for
Communication Situations.
SIAM Journal on Discrete
Harrison, B. (1992). Industrial districts: old wine in new bottles.
Mathematics,
5(3), 305. doi:10.1137/0405023
Regional Studies,
26(5), 469–483.
Braun, P., McRae-Williams, P., & Lowe, J. (2005). Small Business
Herings, P. J.-J., van der Laan, G., & Talman, D. (2005). The po-
Clustering: Accessing Knowledge through Local Net-
sitional power of nodes in digraphs.
Social Choice and
works.
Journal of New Business Ideas & Trends,
3(2),
Welfare,
24(3), 439–454. Retrieved from http://www.
Bryant, K., & Wells, A. (1998). A New School of Thought. In
Jacobs, D., & De Man, A. P. (1996). Clusters, industrial policy
A. Wells (Ed.),
A New Economic Paradigm? Innovation-
and firm strategy: a menu approach.
Technology Analy-
based Evolutionary Systems (Vol. Discussion, pp. 1–4).
sis and Strategic Management,
8(4), 425–437.
Canberra: Dept. Industry Sciencer and Resources, Com-
monwealth of Australia.
Ketels, C. H. M. (2004). European Clusters.
Innovative City and
Business Regions (Vol. 3 Structur, pp. 1–5). Bollsch-
Béal, S., Durieu, J., & Solal, P. (2008). Farsighted coalitional sta-
weil, Germany: Hagbarth Publications. Retrieved from
bility in TU-games.
Mathematical Social Sciences,
56(3),
Béal, S., Rémila, E., & Solal, P. (2010). On the number of blocks
Ketels, C. H. M., & Sölvell, Ö. (2004).
State of the Region Report
required to access the core.
2004: Competitiveness in the Baltic Sea Region (p. 38).
Copenhagen & Stockholm. Retrieved from http://www.
Dubey, P. (1975). On the uniqueness of the Shapley value.
In-
ternational Journal of Game Theory,
4(3), 131–139.
Kóczy, L. Á. (2006). The Core can be Accessed with a Bounded
Number of Blocks.
Journal of Mathematical Economics,
Enright, M. J. (2000). The Globalization of Competition and
the Localization of Competitive Advantage: Policies to-
wards Regional Clustering. In S. Young (Ed.),
The Glo-
Kóczy, L. Á., & Lauwers, L. (2004). The Coalition Structure Core
balization of Multinational Enterprise Activity and Eco-
is Accessible.
Games and Economic Behavior,
48, 86–
nomic Development (pp. 303–326). Houndsmill, Great
Britain: Macmillan.
European Cluster Conference. (2012). Vienna Cluster Manifes-
to: Using excellent clusters to strengthen and restruc-
ture EU industry. Vienna.
Kóczy, L. Á., & Lauwers, L. (2007). The Minimal Dominant Set
United States of America,
36, 48–49. Retrieved from
is a Non-Empty Core-Extension.
Games and Economic
Behavior,
61(2), 277–298.
Nash, J. F. (1953). Two-person cooperative games.
Economet-
Leana, C., & Buren, H. (1999). Organizational social capital and
rica,
21, 128–140. Retrieved from http://www.jstor.org/
employment practices.
The Academy of Management
Review,
24(3), 538–556.
Neyman, a. (1989). Uniqueness of the Shapley value.
Games
Littlechild, S. C., & Thompson, G. F. (1977). Aircraft landing
and Economic Behavior,
1, 116–118. doi:10.1016/0899-
fees: a game theory approach.
The Bell Journal of Eco-
nomics,
8(1), 186–204. doi:10.2307/3003493
Porter, M. E. (1990).
The competitive advantage of nations.
Lämmer-Gamp, T., Meier zu Köcker, G., & Christensen, T. A.
New York: The Free Press.
(2011).
Clusters Are Individuals: Creating Economic
Growth through Cluster Policies for Cluster Manage-
Porter, M. E. (1998). Clusters and the New Economics of Com-
ment Excellence (p. 160). Berlin. Retrieved from http://
petition.
Harvard Business Review, (November-Decem-
ber), 77–90.
Putnam, R. (2000).
Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival of
American Community. New York: Simon and Schuster.
Marshall, A. (1890).
Principles of Economics (Vol. 1). London:
Rosenfeld, S. A. (1997). Bringing Business Clusters into the
Mainstream of Economic Development.
European Plan-
ning Studies,
5(1), 3–23.
McRae-Williams, P. (2004). Cluster strength and structure: How
does this impact on the complementarity of a regions
Rosenfeld, S. A. (2001). Backing into Clusters: Retrofitting Pub-
wine and tourism industries?
Creating Tourism Knowl-
lic Policies.
Intergrating Pressures: Lessions from Around
edge – CAUTHE 14th International Conference for the
the World, John F. Kennedy School Symposium. Harvard
Council for Australian University Tourism and Hospital-
ity Education (p. 8). Ballarat. Retrieved from http://re-
Shapley, L. S. (1953). A Value for n-Person Games. In H. W.
Kuhn & A. W. Tucker (Eds.),
Contributions to the Theory
of Games (Vol. II, pp. 307–317). Princeton University
Meier zu Köcker, G., & Kind, S. (2012). Measuring effects and
impacts of clusters and networks – But how? Evaluation
and impact approaches clusters and networks.
Tactics
Shapley, L. S. (1967). On Balanced Sets and Cores.
Naval Re-
Reflection Group meeting, Brussels, 15 March 2012.
search Logistics Quarterly,
14(4), 453–460. doi:10.1002/
Michael, E. J. (2003). Tourism micro-clusters.
Tourism Econom-
Shapley, L. S. (1971). Cores of convex games.
International Jour-
ics,
9(2), 13. doi:10.5367/000000003101298312
nal of Game Theory,
1(1), 11–26. Retrieved from http://
Nahapiet, J., & Ghoshal, S. (1998). Social Capital, Intellectual
Capital, and the Organizational Advantage.
The Acad-
Shubik, M., & Wooders, M. H. (1983). Approximate cores of
emy of Management Review,
23(2), 242–266. Retrieved
replica games and economies. Part I: Replica games, ex-
ternalities, and approximate cores.
Mathematical Social
Sciences,
6, 27–48.
Nash, J. F. (1950). Equilibrium points in n-person games.
Pro-
ceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the
Straffin, P. D., & Heaney, J. P. (1981). Game theory and the ten-
Wikipedia contributors. (2012). Alfred Marshall.
Wikipedia. Re-
nessee valley authority.
International Journal of Game
Theory,
10(1), 35–43. doi:10.1007/BF01770069
Strauss, J. R. (2010). Capitalising on the value in relationships:
Yang, Y.-Y. (2010). On the accessibility of the core.
Games
A social capital-based model for non-profit public re-
and Economic Behavior,
69(1), 194 – 199. Retrieved
lations.
PRism,
7(2). Retrieved from http://www.prism-
Zaratiegui, J. M. (2002).
Alfred Marshall y la teoría económica
Verbeek, H. (1999).
Innovative Clusters: Identification of value-
del empresario. Valladolid: Universidad de Valladolid,
adding production chains and their networks of inno-
Secretariado de Publicaciones. Retrieved from http://
vation, an international study. Erasmus University, Rot-
von Neumann, J., & Morgenstern, O. (1944).
Theory of Games
Watson, G. W., & Papamarcos, S. D. (2002). Social capital and
and Economic Behavior. Princeton: Princeton University
organizational commitment.
Journal of Business and Psy-
chology,
16(4), 537–552. doi:10.1023/A:1015498101372
VIII Authors
Dr Zita Zombori
Dr László Á. Kóczy
She is working now at the Chemical Works of Gedeon Richter
Graduated from Cambridge he obtained his PhD at the Catho-
Plc. She is responsible for the European Affairs, among others
lic University Leuven. Taught at Maastricht and Óbuda Universi-
for the transnational cooperation aiming to strengthen Rich-
ties, currently he is leading the Game Theory Research Group
ter's position as innovation leader. Between 2008 and 2010 she
at the Research Centre for Economic and Regional Sciences,
headed the Hungarian Pole Program Office. The Program aimed
Hungarian Academy of Sciences, supported by the prestigeous
to create a favourable business environment in the regional
Momentum Programme. He is a specialist in theoretical and
capitals in addition to the Hungarian Cluster Initiative. Before
applied game theory, especially cooperative games with exter-
joining the Pole Program Office she held various positions in
nalities, industrial organization, social choice and scientomet-
the Ministry of Local Government and Regional Development,
rics. He published over 15 academic papers attracting over 100
the National Development Agency and at an intermediary body
for Structural Funds resources. She has an established track-
record of 15 years at the Hungarian Privatization and State
Holding Company and at its predecessors. Her main projects
included privatization and stock and bond issue processes of
major Hungarian companies in the oil and gas, telecommunica-
tion, logistics and pharmaceutical sector among others.
She is a member of the TACTICS Reflection Group and she is
involved in several European projects as well. She is also acting
as a key expert to Polish Working Group on Cluster Policy. She
is designated member of German Cluster Excellence Initiative's
Advisory Board "go-cluster".
Endre Gedai
He is "Integrator", graduate engineer, expert of companies and
of companies' cooperation.
His practical experience in corporate finance had been acquired
between 1990 and 1994 in bank financing and from 1994 to
1998 as managing director of a venture capital company. From
1998 he had been acting as deputy managing director at the
Hungarian Privatization and State Holding Company and as a
member of more Boards and Supervisory Boards he had got
practical experience in corporate management. From 2007 as
colleague of the Hungarian Pole Program Office he has been
dealing with the theoretical and practical research of clusters
and he had taken part in the elaboration of the Hungarian clus-
ter development model.
The Institute for Innovation and Technology (iit) covers the entire
innovation spectrum on a national and transnational level. Its
fundamental elements are the provision of assistance, analysis,
evaluation, moderation and the accompaniment of innovative
systems and clusters. Its departments provide the basis for
these services and are as follows: Innovation Systems and
Clusters, Innovation Support, Predicting Success of Collaborate
R&D Projects, Safety and Security Systems, Innovation Life
Sciences, Evaluation in the area of technology and innovation
policy as well as Technical Education and Training.
More than 70 scientific employees are part of the team and
contribute their technological and socio-economic expertise to
project management. Their competencies range from diverse
natural sciences, engineering and social sciences to economics.
Countries all over the world look for ways to increase their competitiveness. The contribution of
cooperating companies in the form of clusters is rather substantial and therefore, for example, the
European Union and its member states have long been supporting these cooperative efforts. This
support may take the form of a more entrepreneur-friendly legal environment, initiate cooperation,
but it may also mean non-returnable financial contribution.
This paper introduces an entirely novel way to study clusters by looking at the selfish, profit-seeking
interests of the entrepreneurs, the actors of clusters. The approach, using game theory provides an
exact, mathematical framework to study the conflict between the fruitful cooperation represented by
the cluster and the selfish ways of the actors to follow their own – possibly short term – interests. The
game theoretic approach makes it possible to identify not only good or bad clusters, provide recipes
for solutions in some of the bad clusters, but also to define golden rules that do not only facilitate the
evaluation of existing clusters, but help future cluster managers to create better, more stable clusters.
Das Internet der Dinge –
Basis für die IKT-Infrastruktur von morgen
Anwendungen, Akteure und politische Handlungsfelder
Peter Gabriel, Katrin Gaßner, Sebastian Lange
Source: http://www.ictcluster.bg/_Code/UserFiles/Files/2.%20iit_Cluster_Games.pdf
Ardex WPM 299 (Seam Primer) Hazard Alert Code: HIGH Chemwatch Material Safety Data SheetIssue Date: 2-Sep-2008 Version No:5 Page 1 of 24 Section 1 - CHEMICAL PRODUCT AND COMPANY IDENTIFICATION PRODUCT NAMEArdex WPM 299 (Seam Primer) SYNONYMS"lap jointing primer for EPDM and butyl membranes", "Butynol Seam Primer"
ELI's 2nd conference on: "Refractory Hodgkin Lymphoma" Lyon, September 27th and 28th 2012 HL is nowadays a highly curable disease with chemotherapy, with 95%, 85% and 75-80% overall survival (OS) for favorable early-stage disease, unfavorable early-stage disease and advanced stage disease, respectively.1,2,3 Cumulative relative survival has improved through decades with various change in chemotherapy agents, aiming better first complete remission (CR) achievement, but also fewer late toxicity. With first line therapy still being a controverted issue, there is no clear salvage standard for early relapsing or refractory patients.